UCLA Law Review
April, 1990
37 UCLA L. Rev. 693-731
The Leasing Monopolist
John Shepard Wiley Jr. * and
Eric Rasmusen ** and J. Mark Ramseyer ***
* Professor of Law, University of California, Los Angeles; A.B. 1975,
University of California, Davis; M.A. 1980, University of California, Berkeley;
J.D. 1980, University of California, Berkeley.
** Assistant Professor of Business Economics, Anderson Graduate School of
Management, University of California, Los Angeles; B.A. 1980, M.A. 1980, Yale
University; Ph.D. 1984, Massachusetts Institute of Technology.
*** Professor of Law, University of California, Los Angeles; B.A. 1976, Goshen
College; A.M. 1978, University of Michigan; J.D. 1982, Harvard University.
We thank Stephen Breyer, William Comanor, Frank Easterbrook, Franklin Fisher,
William Klein, Thomas Krattenmaker, and Stanley Ornstein for helpful comments.
Copyright 1990 Wiley, Rasmusen, and Ramseyer.
ABSTRACT
The
United Shoe case banned lease-only policies by monopolists. But the court erred in believing
that monopoly pricing could explain United Shoe Machinery's complex of leasing
policies. At best, this explanation only accounts for a few details of the
case. The bulk of the company's conduct seems simply efficient --
suggesting that the
Shoe decision was wrong and its later precedential consequences pernicious.
The Coase Conjecture might seem to make some sense
of
Shoe's
ban on monopoly leasing, and
suggests that the
Shoe rule may have been too narrow. At the same time, however, the Conjecture
dictates that the
Shoe rule be confined ways the opinion did not suggest that are
unacceptably costly to accomplish. Courts would do well to accept that Coase
describes a problem that is real. But they would also do well to accept it as a
problem not worth solving.
INTRODUCTION
Antitrust law regulates the behavior of monopolists by branding some acts as
"bad conduct." To define this key notion, every antitrust casebook includes the
United Shoe Machinery decision, a classic district court opinion that condemned a monopoly firm's
practice of only leasing and never selling its shoe manufacturing equipment. n1
The Supreme Court has never questioned its approval of the case, and
Shoe has provided the authority for later and successful government attacks on
leasing policies in the computer and copier markets. n2 Nonetheless, because
the
Shoe court never correctly
[*694] evaluated the economic impact of leasing, the decision remains highly
unsatisfactory. Although the court condemned leasing because of its
exclusionary effects, most leasing arrangements are no more exclusionary than
sales.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n1
United States v. United Shoe Mach. Corp., 110 F. Supp. 295 (D. Mass. 1953),
aff'd,
347 U.S. 521 (1954).
n2 For example, in 1956 IBM complied with a Justice Department consent decree
requiring it to offer its computers for sale. Nonetheless, most consumers
continued to rent.
See J. SOMA, THE COMPUTER INDUSTRY 35, 61-62 (1976). The Department of Justice
again attacked IBM's rental policies in a suit that the Reagan administration
eventually dismissed.
See F. FISHER, J. McGOWAN
& J. GREENWOOD, FOLDED, SPINDLED, AND MUTILATED: ECONOMIC ANALYSIS AND
U.S. v. IBM 191-96 (1983). In 1975, the Federal Trade Commission entered a consent decree
with Xerox that declared that the firm had followed
"a lease only policy" that was among its violations of federal antitrust law.
In re Xerox Corp., 86 F.T.C. 364, 367-68 (1975)
Cf.
United States v. Am. Can Co., 1950-1 Trade Cas. (CCH) P62,679, at p. 63, 963, 63,968 (1950) (final judgment finding antitrust violation expresses policy favoring customer
ownership of defendant's products
"as compared with the continued leasing of them").
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
If the defendant United Shoe Machinery Corporation did not lease in order to
exclude its competitors, the question remains why it
did insist that its customers lease. Perhaps leasing was incidental to particular
United practices that were in fact exclusionary, that bore no necessary
relationship to leasing, and that caused the
Shoe court to err by condemning leasing generally. Or perhaps both United and its
customers preferred leases and United's various other practices for benign
reasons, and antitrust law ought to discard
Shoe altogether. But an idea of Ronald Coase, from an article written some
twenty years after the
Shoe decision, suggests that leases may enable monopolists to earn monopoly returns
where sales would not. Although the
Shoe court had no chance to consider Coase's later insight, prominent commentators
have noted the connection between that case and the
"Coase Conjecture" -- a theory that explains why leasing can be attractive to a monopolist that
makes goods which are
durable. n3
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n3 Coase,
Durability and Monopoly,
15 J.L. & ECON. 143 (1972). We acquiesce in the conventional label for this Coase insight -- which he
expressed entirely in English -- without endorsing the condescension that
mathematical economists might imply by their use of the label.
For reasons different from Coase's, the durability of a good may make any
competition that does exist more intense than otherwise.
See Carlton
& Gertner,
Market Power and Mergers in Durable-Goods Industries, 32
J.L.
& Econ. S203 (1989).
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
Coase's logic is brilliantly counterintuitive. Usually a firm's products are
complements of each other because greater output enhances the value of
production by creating a reputation in customers' minds. But a monopolist that
makes long-lived goods -- like diamonds, paintings, or aluminum ingots -- faces
an unusual situation. Customers can accelerate or delay their purchases in
anticipation of changing prices, but when customers do buy, they leave the
market until their good wears out. As a result, each future unit of output
potentially is a substitute for every present unit.
The fact that some customers value the good more highly than others tempts the
monopolist to price-discriminate through time: to sell at a high price to
willing buyers today, and then to discount in the future for customers
further down the demand curve who were
[*695] unwilling to pay the initial price. The initial high-valuation customers (the
"Highs") would be willing to pay a high price rather than not obtain the good at all.
But they would not be willing to pay the high price if they foresaw a price
drop. Hence, the monopolist cannot succeed in having a high price today and a
low price tomorrow.
Unfortunately for the monopolist, while it cannot price-discriminate, neither
can it credibly claim that it will maintain its high price forever. After the
Highs have made their purchases, a rational monopolist has no reason not to try
to sell to the low-valuation customers (the
"Lows") left in the market. As the Highs have already bought, the monopolist may as
well lower its price and sell to the Lows. But foreseeing that price drop, the
Highs will not buy in the first place. The
only outcome that does not create a logical contradiction is for the price to
be low today and low tomorrow. The Coase Conjecture is a paradox: the
durability of the monopolist's goods denies it its monopoly profit.
Coase also showed that the monopolist can escape this unprofitable paradox by
leasing instead of selling. By selling the good at a high price, the monopolist
removes the high-valuation customers from the market and encounters the
temptation to lower the price. But when the monopolist leases the good at a
high rental charge, the high-valuation customers remain in the market, and the
monopolist has no incentive to lower the future rental charge. Leasing enables
the monopolist essentially to switch from selling a durable good to selling the
nondurable service flow that a durable good produces. By thus retaining an
incentive to maintain high rental charges, the monopolist can convince
customers willing to
pay those charges to do so immediately -- because they have no reason to expect
a future drop in charges -- and can thereby earn a supracompetitive profit. n4
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n4 Coase also explained that a monopolist can take two other steps to gain its
monopoly profit: make the product less durable or offer to repurchase the
machines at a set price. Coase,
supra note 3, at 149.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
In the last ten years, the Coase Conjecture has become an important part of
industrial organization theory, n5 and prominent economists have continued to
produce increasingly sophisticated elaborations on it. Faruk Gul, Hugo
Sonnenschein, and Robert Wilson made Coase's intuitive discussion precise with
mathematical
[*696] game theory. n6 Jeremy Bulow constructed a simpler but classic two-period
model of a durable-goods monopoly and explored how durable
a monopolist would choose to make the product it sells. n7 Eric Bond and Larry
Samuelson discussed what happens if buyers eventually replace the
"durable" goods. n8 Sam Bucovetsky, John Chilton, and Valerie Suslow asked how Coase's
logic affected the way a monopolist would choose to exclude potential
competitors. n9 Nancy Stokey explored what happens if a seller cannot change
prices quickly. n10 Faruk Gul n11 and Lawrence Ausubel and Raymond Deneckere
n12 extended the Coase Conjecture to oligopolistic durable-goods sellers.
Charles Kahn asked what would happen if marginal costs increased with output.
n13
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n5 Note, for example, the extensive discussion of the Conjecture in a recent
text, J. TIROLE, THE THEORY OF INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION 72-74, 79-87, 91-92
(1988).
n6 Gul, Sonnenschein
&
Wilson,
Foundations of Dynamic Monopoly and the Coase Conjecture, 39 J. ECON. THEORY 155 (1986).
n7 Answer: Not very. Bulow,
Durable-Goods Monopolists, 90 J. POL. ECON. 314 (1982) [hereinafter Bulow,
Monopolists]; Bulow,
An Economic Theory of Planned Obsolescence, 101 Q.J. ECON. 729, 733 n.10 (1986) [hereinafter Bulow,
Planned Obsolescence]. For a numerical example of the Bulow model, see E. RASMUSEN, GAMES AND
INFORMATION 276-80 (1989).
See also Rust,
When is it Optimal to Kill off the Market for Used Durable Goods?, 54 ECONOMETRICA 65 (1986) (when consumers can choose when to scrap the
product, the monopolist may make it of either socially excessive or socially
deficient durability).
n8 Answer: The monopolist may be able to sell the product at a monopoly price
after all. Bond
& Samuelson,
Durable Good Monopolies with Rational Expectations and Replacement Sales, 15 RAND J. ECON. 336 (1984). K. Sridhar Moorthy found the same result follows
if the monopolist is able to trick consumers into believing that its actually
high rate of future production instead will be low. Moorthy,
Consumer Expectations and the Pricing of Durables, in ISSUES IN PRICING 99 (T. Devinney ed. 1988).
n9 Answer: By selling rather than by leasing.
See Bucovetsky
& Chilton,
Concurrent Renting and Selling in a Durable-Goods Monopoly Under Threat of Entry, 17 RAND J. ECON. 261 (1986); Suslow,
Commitment and Monopoly Pricing in Durable Goods Models, 4 INT'L J. INDUS. ORG. 451 (1986). When a potential competitor considers
challenging a monopolist, the competitor first asks whether the monopolist
would be
willing to wage a price war. Because a leasing monopolist owns the durable
goods in use, a price war would reduce the capital value of the monopolist's
own assets -- hence, the lessor-monopolist will hesitate to cut prices. By
contrast, the seller-monopolist will cut prices more willingly, as any decline
in the value of the existing assets falls on consumers who have already bought
the assets. The same point appears in Bulow,
Planned Obsolescence, supra note 7, at 743-46.
n10 Answer: The monopolist may be able to charge monopoly prices to some
buyers. Stokey,
Rational Expectations and Durable Goods Pricing, 12 BELL. J. ECON. 112 (1981).
n11 Gul,
Noncooperative Collusion in Durable Goods Oligopoly, 18 RAND J. ECON. 248 (1987). Gul's model yields a curious result:
"For the durable goods model, monopoly is more competitive than oligopoly:
higher total profits and prices can be sustained under oligopoly than under
monopoly."
Id. at 249.
n12 Ausubel
& Deneckere,
One Is Almost Enough for Monopoly, 18 RAND J. ECON. 255 (1987). This model yields results similar to those in
Gul,
supra note 11.
n13 Answer: The Coase Conjecture is less applicable. Kahn,
Durable Goods Monopolist and Consistency with Increasing Costs, 54 ECONOMETRICA 275 (1986).
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
[*697] As hostile as Chicago economists usually are toward efforts by judges to
intervene in the market, Ronald Coase has apparently invented a widely accepted
theory that requires just such intervention. Richard Posner, author of a
classic Chicago antitrust monograph and now a distinguished federal judge, has
adopted exactly this tack.
After explaining flaws in the
Shoe court opinion, Posner cites the Coase Conjecture as a possible motivation for
the lease-only policy:
"Professor Coase has argued that the lease-only policy of a monopolist of a
durable good, such as United Shoe Machinery Corporation, may be designed to
overcome the difficulties encountered in trying to charge a monopoly price for
a durable good." n14 Yet if antitrust law aims to force sellers to price at competitive levels,
then the Coase Conjecture implies that judges should embrace the
Shoe ban on lease-only monopoly. Posner makes just this suggestion:
"Perhaps the lease-only policy should have been forbidden on that ground . . . ." n15
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n14 R. POSNER, ANTITRUST LAW: AN ECONOMIC PERSPECTIVE 184 (1976);
see also R. POSNER
& F. EASTERBROOK, ANTITRUST: CASES, ECONOMIC NOTES AND OTHER MATERIALS
627 (2d ed. 1981); Froeb,
Evaluating Mergers in Durable Goods Industries,
34 ANTITRUST BULL. 99 (1989).
n15 R. POSNER,
supra note 14, at 184.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
In delightful irony, however, it is not Posner's Coase-based suggestion but
rather the usual Chicago reluctance to interfere in the market that gives the
right result in this case. True enough, in one respect the Coase Conjecture
does support the
Shoe rule; indeed, it suggests that courts should broaden the rule significantly.
In other ways, though, the Conjecture implies that judges ought to narrow the
Shoe rule, for the Conjecture applies only under stringent qualifications -- and
the rule certainly was not appropriate in the
Shoe case itself. These qualifications imply that courts should either bound
Shoe's proscription with a large number of inevitably
arbitrary lines, or scrap the
Shoe rule altogether. We argue the latter. In no event should a court consider
Shoe's ban on lease-only conduct to be sensible law.
I. THE
SHOE CASES
The United Shoe Machinery Corporation may be the most popular antitrust
defendant of all time. Plaintiffs have taken it from district courts to the
Supreme Court six times in one century. The federal government first (and
unsuccessfully) claimed a criminal violation of the Sherman Act by five
individuals who in 1899 merged their companies to create the United Shoe Machinery
Company.
[*698] Holmes's unanimous 1913 opinion upheld the district court's dismissal of the
attack on the merger. n16 Again using the Sherman Act, the government sued the
corporate entity United Shoe Machinery Company for the same merger, n17 as well as for a
number of its standard
leasing clauses (which Justice Louis Brandeis had drafted in private practice).
n18 In 1918, the Supreme Court upheld the merger against this second challenge
and approved United's leasing practices for the first time. n19 On a third try
in 1922, invoking the Clayton Act of 1914, the government finally succeeded in
winning Supreme Court condemnation of specific lease clauses although not of
United's general leasing policy. n20
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n16
United States v. Winslow, 227 U.S. 202 (1913). In addition to the merger, the government also sought to attack the merged
defendants' practice of
ceasing to sell shoe machinery to the shoe manufacturers. Instead, they only
let machines, and on the condition that unless the shoe manufacturers use only
machines of the kinds mentioned furnished by the defendants, or if they use any
such machines furnished by other
machinery makers, then all machines let by the defendants shall be taken away.
This condition they constantly have enforced.
Id. at 216.
Justice Holmes, however, ruled that that conduct was not before the Court, and
"the combination was simply an effort after greater efficiency."
Id. at 217;
see also
United States v. United Shoe Mach. Co., 222 F. 349 (D. Mass. 1915),
aff'd,
247 U.S. 32 (1918) (also endorsing an efficiency interpretation of the merger). Supporting
Holmes's efficiency view are the facts that the merged company combined
previously separate operations into a single new plant in Beverly,
Massachusetts and created new service and research departments. C. KAYSEN,
UNITED STATES V. UNITED SHOE MACHINERY CORPORATION 9-10 (1956). For an
interpretation of the merger that stresses its anticompetitive character (and
does not discuss these facts), see Bittlingmayer,
Did Antitrust Cause the
Great Merger Wave?,
28 J.L. & ECON. 77, 102-03 & n.54 (1985) (arguing that early and successful price-fixing prosecution channeled cartel
efforts into merger activity and supporting this claim in the
Shoe instance with testimony from a lawyer involved in the merger). Of course, a
merger can both increase productive efficiency and facilitate monopoly pricing.
See Williamson,
Economies as an Antitrust Defense: The Welfare Tradeoffs,
58 AM. ECON. REV. 18 (1968).
n17 The government could relitigate the same issue because of the preclusion
requirement of mutuality which modern procedure has abandoned.
See
Parklane Hosiery Co. v. Shore, 439 U.S. 322 (1979);
Blonder-Tongue Laboratories v. University of Ill. Found., 402 U.S. 313 (1971).
n18 C. KAYSEN,
supra note 16, at 15 n.38.
n19
United States v. United Shoe Mach. Co., 247 U.S. 32 (1918). Half a century later, the Supreme Court said that the 1918 Court's reasons for
vindicating United's lease terms were
"not clear."
Hanover Shoe, Inc. v. United Shoe Mach. Corp., 392 U.S. 481, 500 (1968).
n20
United Shoe Mach. Corp. v. United States, 258 U.S. 451 (1922). The Court rejected United's defense of res judicata by holding that the
Clayton Act cause of action differed from the previous Sherman Act claims.
Id. at 460. The Court enjoined United's use of seven particular types of lease clauses,
concluding that
"while the clauses enjoined do not contain specific agreements not to use the
machinery of a competitor of the lessor, the practical effect of these drastic
provisions is to prevent such use."
Id. at 457. The specific clauses were the following:
(1) the restricted use clause, which provides that the leased machinery shall
not . . . be used upon shoes . . . upon which certain other operations have not
been performed on other machines of the defendants; (2) the exclusive use
clause, which provides that if the lessee fails to use exclusively machinery of
certain kinds made by the lessor, the lessor shall have the right to cancel the
right to use all such machinery so leased; (3) the supplies clause, which
provides that the lessee shall purchase supplies exclusively from the lessor;
(4) the patent insole clause, which provides that the lessee shall only use
machinery leased on shoes which have had certain other operations performed
upon them by the defendants' machines; (5) the additional machinery clause,
which provides that the lessee shall take all additional machinery for certain
kinds of work from the lessor or lose his right to retain the machines which he
has already leased; (6) the
factory output clause, which requires the payment of a royalty on shoes
operated upon by machines made by competitors; (7) the discriminatory royalty
clause, providing lower royalty for lessees who agree not to use certain
machinery on shoes lasted on machines other than those leased from the lessor.
Id. at 456-57.
The Court rejected United's defense that it offered an alternative lease free
of restrictions but which required an initial cash payment. This unrestricted
lease option more closely resembled a sale, but the required initial payment
was so large that
"no manufacturer ever chooses the unrestricted lease."
United States v. United Shoe Mach. Co., 264 F. 138, 164 (E.D. Mo. 1920),
aff'd,
258 U.S. 451 (1922). The Supreme Court held that
"the fact that a form of lease was offered which is not the subject of
controversy is
not a justification of the use of clauses in other leases which we find to be
violative of the act."
258 U.S. at 464.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
[*699] In 1947, the government sued a fourth time, now attacking aspects of leasing
that had survived the third challenge. n21 After a
"trial of prodigious length," n22 District Judge Wyzanski ruled in 1953 that United had violated the Sherman
Act. He found that the company had monopoly power (more than seventy-five
percent of the shoe machinery market) and had used many objectionable
practices. Central to his holding was United's exclusive reliance on leasing
for its most important machines. n23 According to the court, this
[*700] practice
"created barriers to entry by competitors into the shoe machinery field." n24 Judge Wyzanski condemned the
complex of obligations and rights [that] deter a shoe manufacturer from
disposing of a United machine and acquiring
a competitor's machine. He is deterred more than if he owned that same United
machine, or if he held it on a short lease carrying simple rental provisions
and a reasonable charge for [cancellation] before the end of the term. n25
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n21
United States v. United Shoe Mach. Corp., 110 F. Supp. 295 (D. Mass. 1953). As the district court explained the prosecution:
Until Alcoa lost its case in 1945, there was no significant reason to suppose
that United's conduct violated
� 2 of the Sherman Act. . . . What United is now doing is similar to what it was
then doing, but the activities which were similar stood uncondemned, -- indeed,
one ought to go further and say they were in part endorsed.
Id. at 348. The court did allow that the doctrine of res judicata protected the original
merger.
Id. at 344.
n22
Id. at 298. The trial lasted for
121 days, generating 14,194 pages of transcript and 26,474 pages of exhibits.
Id. at 299.
n23
"Of the 342 machine types now marketed by United, United offers 178 on lease
basis only, 42 on sale basis only, and 122 on alternate lease or sale terms at
the customer's option. . . . Those of more importance for the shoe manufacturer
are offered only for lease."
Id. at 314.
n24
Id. at 340. The circuit court in the third prosecution specifically declared that United's
leasing system in itself was
not a violation of the Clayton Act. C. KAYSEN,
supra note 16, at 15 (citing
264 F. 138).
n25
110 F. Supp. at 340.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
This
"complex of obligations and rights" arose from the leases' ten-year terms (which United enforced in a
discriminatory fashion), n26 the
"full
capacity clause," n27 the deferred payment charge (or
"return charge"), n28 and the
"free repair clause." n29 Judge Wyzanski
[*701] further condemned United for earning different rates of return on different
lines of machines, depending on whether or not the firm faced competition in a
particular line. n30 As relief, the court ordered United to offer its machines
for sale. It permitted United to continue leasing, but only under certain
conditions: at nondiscriminatory rates; for no more than a five-year term; with
no full capacity clause; and with separate repair charges. n31 On the same day
it decided
Brown v. Board of Education, n32 the Supreme Court affirmed the district court in a single sentence. n33
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n26
"When a lessee desires to replace a United machine, United gives him more
favorable terms if the replacement is by another United machine than if it is
by a competitive machine."
Id. at 340. United required
partial payment of full lease obligations if a lessee returned a machine to replace it
with a competitor's machine. United did not make a similar demand when lessees
returned machines for such other reasons as the following: they had abandoned
use of that machine's particular operation; they began to perform it by hand;
the United machine had not operated as anticipated; or they sought a different
United machine.
Id. at 320. The court said
"the discrimination is designed to operate as, and does operate as, a method of
excluding from the shoe factories shoe machinery competitive with United."
Id. at 321.
The earlier Clayton Act adjudication had declared that the 17-year term of
United's previous lease
"is not prohibited by the statute."
264 F. at 168.
n27 United's standard
lease provided that
"the lessee shall use the leased machinery to its full capacity . . . ."
110 F. Supp. at 316. The district court reported that United applied this term if
"the lessee fails to use the machine on work for which the machine is capable of
being used, and instead performs such work by using a competitor's machine."
Id. at 320. The government offered 90 instances of United's use of the capacity (or a
similar) clause. For example,
"from 1931 to 1935 Florsheim wanted to return 5 United machines covered by
unexpired leases, and substitute competitors' machines, but United insisted on
the lease terms, including the full capacity clause."
Id. at 321. United also
"bill[ed] its customers under the full capacity clause when competitive machines
were used . . . ."
Id. The previous government challenge also had failed against this clause.
See C. KAYSEN,
supra note
16, at 15 (citing
264 F. 138);
see also infra notes 84-91 and accompanying text.
n28 United levied this type of charge on all lessees when they returned the
machine to United, at either the conclusion or the termination of the lease.
110 F. Supp. at 320.
See
Equipment Distrib. Coalition v. FCC, 824 F.2d 1197, 1202 (D.C. Cir. 1987). The court found it objectionable that return charges
"can in practice, through the right of deduction fund, be reduced to
insignificance if [the lessee] keeps this and other United machines to the end
of the periods for which [the lessee] leased them.
110 F. Supp. at 340;
see infra note 65.
n29
110 F. Supp. at 340;
see infra text accompanying notes 60-61.
n30
Id. at 340-41;
see infra notes 62-65 and accompanying text. In
addition, the district court faulted United for acquiring patents and for
purchasing second-hand shoe machines for scrap. But the court made only
"brief reference" to these factors after it had outlined the other
"principal sources of United's power."
Id. at 344. The extent of United's latter practice was
"trivial."
See C. KAYSEN,
supra note 16, at 113.
n31 The court also barred United from distributing others' machines; from
continuing to own certain subsidiaries; and from refraining to license its
patents to competitors.
110 F. Supp. at 346-54.
n32
347 U.S. 483 (1954).
n33
347 U.S. 521 (1954). United Shoe made two more forays to the Supreme Court. Trip five arose from
the government's ultimately successful effort to obtain additional relief,
including divestiture.
See
United States v. United Shoe Mach. Corp., 391 U.S. 244 (1968);
see also
1969 Trade Cas. (CCH) P72688 (D. Mass.) (United agreed both to sell assets to reduce its size to one-third
of the market and to additional patent licensing). Trip six was a successful
"me too" suit for damages by a private plaintiff.
See
Hanover Shoe, Inc. v. United Shoe Mach. Corp., 392 U.S. 481 (1968).
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
Judge Wyzanski's 1953
Shoe opinion established a rule against lease-only monopoly -- or so the Supreme
Court said in 1968, seven votes to one. n34 This interpretation remains the
dominant one, n35 but it has been clouded recently by two circuit courts that,
while acknowledging the
Shoe ban on lease-only policies, found that such
[*702] policies were not illegal in their cases. n36 Our focus is
upon the wisdom of this controversial lease-only holding, rather than on the
separate concern that individual lease clauses amounted to exclusionary
promises by lessees not to patronize United's competitors. n37
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n34
See
Hanover Shoe, 392 U.S. at 484-87 (Wyzanski's opinion outlawed United's lease-only policy in and of itself and
apart from the
"certain clauses in the standard lease" that it also condemned);
see also
id. at 511 (Stewart, J., dissenting) (arguing that
Shoe
"held unlawful only particular kinds of leases with particular provisions, not
United's general practice of leasing only") (footnote omitted);
see also supra note 2 and accompanying text.
Leasing was at issue in various private suits against IBM in the 1970s and
early 1980s.
See, e.g.,
Transamerica Computer Co. v. International Business Mach. Corp., 698 F.2d 1377, 1382 (9th Cir.),
cert. denied,
464 U.S. 955 (1983);
Telex Corp. v. International Business Mach. Corp., 510 F.2d 894, 919-28 (10th Cir.),
cert. denied,
423 U.S. 802 (1975). But such cases are not pertinent to our discussion because IBM during this
time operated under a consent decree that forced it to offer a sales option.
See supra note 2.
n35
See, e.g., Robinson,
Recent Antitrust Developments -- 1979,
80 COLUM. L. REV. 1, 4 (1980) (Judge Wyzanski found United Shoe Machinery had run afoul of monopoly law
"because it employed a restrictive 'lease only' policy which excluded actual and
potential competition.").
n36 In
Williamsburg Wax Museum v. Historic Figures, Inc., 810 F.2d 243, 253 (D.C. Cir. 1987) (citing but without explanation ignoring
Hanover Shoe), Judge Mikva allowed leasing because the defendant in fact did sometimes sell
the product and because (unlike in
United Shoe) there was not an
"entire panoply of practices."
Id. The Ninth Circuit allowed leasing in
Souza v. Estate of Bishop, 821 F.2d 1332, 1337 (9th Cir. 1987) (failing to cite
Hanover Shoe), because it
"creates no continuing relationship between lessor and lessee" and involves no
"terms that inhibit lessees from purchasing or leasing land owned by other
landholders." Both opinions fail to make clear whether lease-only is impermissible by
itself, or only
"in combination with other practices."
n37 A monopolist may try to insert into a lease exclusionary promises from
customers that they not deal with the monopolist's
competitors. A simple exclusionary promise is illegal under undisputed law.
See infra note 48. But leasing is neither necessary to nor sufficient for such
exclusion. Monopolists can seek such promises independently, or in connection
with contracts for new or continued sales, for service, or for anything else.
Our main attention in this Article is on United's lease-only practice, not on
United's particular lease terms or practices that some have believed amount to
such exclusionary promises. We dispute some of these beliefs in Part II(B) and
discuss the issue at greater length in E. Rasmusen, J.M. Ramseyer
& J. Wiley, Naked Exclusion, UCLA Anderson Graduate School of Management
Business Economics Working Paper #89-17 (1989), and Rasmusen,
Recent Developments in the Economics of Exclusionary Contracts, in THE CENTENARY OF COMPETITION LAW IN CANADA (R.S.
Khemani
& W.T. Stanbury eds.) (forthcoming 1990) (working title). We make two further
observations on this score.
First, if United did bundle any exclusionary clause into its lease, the clause
it bundled was inexplicably generous. The
Shoe court made much of United's policy of charging a lessee more if it returned
the machine to replace it with a rival's than for another reason.
See supra note 26. Yet these assertedly exclusionary charges were considerably less than
the customer's remaining liability under the terms of the lease.
See
110 F. Supp. at 320. A United bent on excluding rivals ought to have insisted on
full liability under the truncated lease.
Second, Kaysen reports that
"it is clear that United does not oppress shoe manufacturers in any way that
makes them generally conscious of such oppression." C. KAYSEN,
supra note 16, at 203. United's supposed efforts to exclude its rivals thus
escaped its customers, who would bear the brunt of being the vehicle for any
real exclusionary scheme.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
One also might read the
Shoe opinion in a far different light: as an artifact of a bygone era in antitrust,
a relic from the days when populist judges aimed the Sherman Act at efficient
firms simply because they were large, rather than to achieve efficient or
proconsumer ends. To support this reading, one would fasten on
Shoe's embrace of Judge Hand's famous
Alcoa opinion, n38 which is unmistakably of this genre and which some have argued is
no
[*703] longer living law. n39 But we doubt
Shoe is dead. No judge has said so. n40 The hornbooks treat it as an important
source of the law of monopoly. n41 A law firm would be courageous (or not
recently in touch with its malpractice carrier) if it counseled a client with
market power to adopt a
Shoe-style lease
policy. The horse we beat is not dead. But as the following Section shows,
neither is it well shod.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n38
United States v. Aluminum Co. of Am., 148 F.2d 416 (2d Cir. 1945);
see supra note 21. Judge Wyzanski had served as law clerk to Judge Learned Hand,
referring to the Judge as one of
"the Hand boys." Richardson,
In Memoriam: Charles E. Wyzanski, Jr.,
100 HARV. L. REV. 723, 726 (1987).
n39
See, e.g., Robinson,
supra note 35, at 1 ("Judge Learned Hand's frequently cited but little understood
Alcoa opinion was given a decent burial by the Second Circuit in
Berkey v. Kodak and replaced with a more realistic and workable concept of monopolization."). To bolster this case, one might note that Judge Wyzanski confessed with
disinterested candor that United Shoe Machinery's illegal practices were not
only a longstanding industry custom to which its customers offered no
complaint, but in some respects actually arose
"to meet their preferences."
110 F. Supp. at 314, 319, 323. One further would note that the court thought it culpable that
"being by far the largest company in the field, with by far the largest
resources in dollars, in patents, in facilities, and in knowledge, United has a
marked capacity to attract offers of inventions, inventors' services, and shoe
machinery businesses."
Id. at 343-44. Finally one would argue that the court appeared to regard United Shoe
Machinery's research and development effort as a reason more to condemn than to
praise the firm.
Id. at 344-46;
see also infra notes 65, 79.
n40
See supra notes
2, 34, 36.
n41
See, e.g., H. HOVENKAMP, ECONOMICS AND FEDERAL ANTITRUST LAW 137 (1985) (offering
portions of
Shoe's analysis as an approximation of
"the prevailing legal rule"); L. SULLIVAN, HANDBOOK OF THE LAW OF ANTITRUST 114 (1977) ("The leasing policy described in
United Shoe Machinery is the best example in the case law of conduct which tends to raise entry
barriers.") (footnote omitted).
But see H. HOVENKAMP,
supra, at 148-49 (impliedly criticizing different
Shoe holding that price discrimination is bad conduct).
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
II. UNDERSTANDING LEASING
A.
The Chicago Critique
A question different from whether the
Shoe rule still reigns is whether it makes sense. One cannot fault Judge Wyzanski
for
"ignoring economics" because in deciding the
Shoe case he had the very latest advice from the Harvard Department of Economics.
After two
years of pretrial proceedings, he had decided to hire as law clerk Carl Kaysen,
then an assistant professor at Harvard. Kaysen taught his classes and attended
parts of the trial by day, read the transcripts at night, eventually wrote his
dissertation about the case, and went on to become a distinguished professor of
industrial organization. n42
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n42
See
Reilly v. United States, 682 F. Supp. 150, 161-62 (D.R.I. 1988) (describing Kaysen's involvement); Kaysen,
In Memoriam: Charles E. Wyzanski, Jr.,
100 HARV. L. REV. 713 (1987). Judge Wyzanski apparently later decided that appointing an economist as clerk
improperly shielded expert testimony from examination by the parties.
Id. at 715.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
[*704] Times change. Two years later, Aaron Director and Edward Levi launched a
different brand of economics: the
Chicago critique of antitrust law. n43 They did so through an article that at
least implicitly attacked
Shoe by challenging the notion that lease-only policies could enable monopolists
profitably to exclude competitors -- a notion central to the
Shoe decision. n44 By the 1970s, this attack had become explicit. Writers like
Robert Bork, n45 Richard Posner, and Frank Easterbrook n46 all directly
criticized the
Shoe court's claim that United could have used its leasing policies to exclude
rivals. They argued that it was not possible for a monopolist to exclude rivals
more successfully with leases than sales. To them, a monopolist could use
leases either to charge monopoly prices or to exclude rivals, but not to do
both. And if using the leases to exclude prevented the monopolist from earning
monopoly returns, then the monopolist would not exclude.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n43 Director
& Levi,
Law and the Future: Trade Regulation,
51 NW. U.L. REV. 281, 290 (1956).
n44
See
110 F. Supp. at 340.
n45
See R. BORK, THE ANTITRUST PARADOX 136-60, 164-75 (1978).
n46
See R. POSNER,
supra note 14, at ch. 8; R. POSNER
& F. EASTERBROOK,
supra note 14, at ch. 6.
Cf.
United States v. Aluminum Co. of Am., 44 F. Supp. 97, 121, 123, 136-38, 143-44 (S.D.N.Y. 1941) (extensive fact survey offers no support for Easterbrook suggestion),
aff'd in part and rev'd in part,
148 F.2d 416 (2d Cir. 1945); G. SMITH, FROM MONOPOLY TO COMPETITION: THE TRANSFORMATIONS OF ALCOA,
1888-1986 80, 94-96 (1988) (more mixed record).
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
Despite its logical clarity, the
Chicago thesis remains problematic. The thesis proceeds in two apparently
straightforward steps: (1) monopolists can never buy inefficient exclusionary
terms for free; and (2) the price for such terms will always make the deal a
bad one for the monopolist. Notwithstanding the clarity, however, at least two
problems remain. First, it is far from certain as a matter of economic theory
that monopolists can never acquire exclusionary terms cheaply -- an issue that
we explore in another paper. n47 Second, real counterexamples do cast doubt on
the Chicago thesis. n48
[*705] For purposes of this Article, therefore, we will not rely upon the Chicago
reasoning in our criticism of
Shoe's rule. n49
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n47 In E. Rasmusen, J.M. Ramseyer
& J. Wiley,
supra note 37, we show why a monopolist may in
fact be able to buy inefficient exclusionary terms at a very low price. Given
certain common and plausible conditions, exclusion may well be a profitable
strategy. Nonetheless, for reasons we outline in Part II(B), we do not believe
the
Shoe leases were exclusionary.
n48
See
Lorain Journal Co. v. United States, 342 U.S. 143 (1951) (newspaper refuses advertising from customers submitting ads to local radio
station);
United States v. Aluminum Co. of Am., 148 F.2d 416, 422 (2d Cir. 1945) (Hand, J.) (Alcoa buys promises from power suppliers not to sell power to
other aluminum companies);
cf. Easterbrook,
Allocating Antitrust Decisionmaking Tasks,
76 GEO. L.J. 305, 315-16 (1987) (offering a speculative efficiency justification for Alcoa's
conduct).
n49 For different arguments that the Chicago analysis of excluding through
leasing is incomplete, see Kaplow,
Extension of Monopoly Power Through Leverage,
85 COLUM. L. REV. 515 (1985).
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
Lease-only policies are not so mysterious as exclusionary promises. In the
following section, we discuss the source of Judge Wyzanski's misunderstandings
and explain why exclusion cannot account for the bulk of United's conduct. We
then outline the motives that
could account for that behavior. Of these, most are innocuous; only the Coase
Conjecture might support
Shoe's rule against lease-only monopolies. In the last Section, however, we explain
why that Conjecture calls not for a ban on leases, but for a rejection of the
Shoe rule.
B.
Fallacies of Exclusion
Judge Wyzanski condemned United conduct that he said was
"exclusionary." Unfortunately, vigorous competition also excludes. A firm that
offers high quality at low price necessarily excludes rivals that offer less
for more. Judge Wyzanski grasped this fundamental when he
"confessed at the outset that any system of selling or leasing one company's
machines will, of course, impede to some extent the distribution of another
company's machines." n50 But he did not heed the implication. To be undesirable, conduct must
violate a more basic antitrust standard: the exclusion must be inefficient or
unfair to consumers. n51 Under a proper analysis, conduct that Judge Wyzanski
condemned is in fact innocuous.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n50
110 F. Supp at 324.
n51 There is controversy over the basic standard by which antitrust law ought
to measure good and evil.
See, e.g., Lande,
The Rise and (Coming) Fall of Efficiency as the Ruler of Antitrust,
33 ANTITRUST BULL. 429 (1988). Consensus that competitive prices are socially preferable to monopoly
prices, however, saves us from having to rehearse this controversy here.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
1. Leasing Only
A monopolist cannot exclude rivals more effectively by leasing exclusively than
by selling. A sale is simply a lease for the life of the product. Short leases
free customers from capital commitments to the monopolist's product. Leasing
thus leaves those customers
more able to switch to a rival. The monopolist's lease-only policy does prevent a
second-hand or recycled market. n52 But it facilitates
[*706] a more effective form of competition: entry by firms that make new competing
goods. n53
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n52 Judge Wyzanski complained about this effect.
See
110 F. Supp. at 325. For a discussion of this form of competition, see Carlton
& Gertner,
supra note 3, at S211-12.
n53
Cf. F. FISHER,
J. McGOWAN
& J. GREENWOOD,
supra note 2, at 195-96 (unwanted leasing encourages new entry and cannot be a
barrier to it).
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
2. Long Terms
Judge Wyzanski thought the length of United's ten-year leases increased their
exclusionary effect. n54 In fact, long-term leases are no more exclusionary
than sales -- even if (as in
Shoe) n55 the leases bar subletting. A monopolist may try to exclude rivals by
satisfying the available demand, but its ability to do so does not depend on
the form of the transaction. What counts is that consumers have patronized the
monopolist -- whether by sale or by lease -- and want to consume no more. Using
either form of transaction, the monopolist can reap its monopoly profit
and nothing greater.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n54
110 F. Supp. at 324-25.
n55
See
id. at 315.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
Consider a market in which the seller has a safe monopoly in period one, but in
period two faces potential entry that it would like to exclude. It can adopt
one of three strategies: (1) outright sales; (2) successive one-period leases;
or (3) long-term leases covering both periods. Although Judge Wyzanski was
vague about the exact mechanics, an argument that long-term leases are more
exclusionary than sales might run as follows. If the monopolist uses the
short-term lease, then entry is easy. The entrant offers a low price in the
second period and can attract the monopolist's customers. If the monopolist
uses outright sale, entry is also easy. The entrant offers a low price in the
second period, and the customer can resell the original purchase and replace it
with one of the entrant's
products. The long-term lease, however, is exclusionary because the monopolist
can include a clause forbidding subletting. Thus, the monopolist commits the
buyer to hold the product for the two-period duration of the lease. Even if the
entrant appears with a lower price, entry is unprofitable because the customer
cannot switch.
This argument errs by ignoring the prices of the lease, of the sale, and of the
resale. To offer a simple example with no discounting, suppose the monopoly
price per period of use is 20, and the competitive price (charged by the
entrant) is 10.
Using a short-term lease, the monopolist can rent the product at a price of 20
for the first period and 10 for the second, for total revenue of 30. The high
monopoly profits in the first period attract
[*707] competitors into the industry, and those new entrants compete away the profits
in the second. n56
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n56 For a discussion of when a monopolist might be able profitably to prevent
entry in the second period, see E. Rasmusen, J.M. Ramseyer
& J. Wiley,
supra note 37.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
Using outright sale, the monopolist can sell the product at a price of 30. If
the monopolist sets the price any higher, it would exceed the customers'
willingness to pay. After all, the monopoly rental charge of 20 for the first
period indicates that customers would pay no more than that for the right to
use the product during that time; and because they expect competitors to enter
in the second period, they will pay no more than 10 for the right to use it
during the second. In a two-period model, therefore, customers will pay a total
price of only 30. If the monopolist charged more, they would switch to the next
best substitute or drop
out of the market in the first period and buy (or rent) from the entrant in the
second. Most importantly, customers who buy in the first period do not benefit
from selling their product in the second to buy from the competitor. When the
competitor appears offering to sell at 10, the resale price falls to 10 as
well. Accordingly, first-period buyers can charge no more than 10 for the
products they bought at 30. Unfortunately for the first-period buyer, there is
no point to selling at 10 to buy at 10. n57
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n57 Moreover, because it would not benefit the buyer to resell, the monopolist
would not hurt the customer by including a no-resale clause in the initial
sales contract.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
For the same reasons, a monopolist who used a long-term lease could charge no
more than 30, although it could allocate this total
over time in a variety of ways. Because the customer is willing to pay a total
of 30 for the right to use the product over the two periods, the customer will
not care whether it pays 20 for the first period and 10 for the second, 15
each, or 10 for the first and 20 for the second. Whatever the allocation of
rent, however, the monopolist cannot do any better with a long-term lease than
with an outright sale, and the customer cannot do worse. n58
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n58 Note, however, that there may be a variety of efficiency reasons for
selecting one form of financing over others.
See infra text accompanying notes 66-91.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
If long-term leases will not increase a monopolist's profits, neither will they
automatically exclude entrants. Absent specifically exclusionary clauses added
to a lease,
long-term leases are no more exclusionary than outright sales. Both sales and
long-term leases deny entrants access to the customers that buy or lease in the
first period. If a long-term lease has a no-sublet clause, it also takes those
customers out of the second-period market. But the same occurs
[*708] with a sale. After all, the first-period sale puts units on the market that
some customer has to own. Both long-term leases and sales, in short, necessarily
reduce the number of customers that entrants can serve, and by the number of
customers willing to pay the monopoly price in the first period. n59
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n59 In fact, even if a monopolist uses short-term leases, the entrant will not
enter if in the second period the monopolist leases at 10. In other words; the
monopolist
can make entry yield zero profits if it is willing to accept zero profits
itself.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
3. Tied Repair Service
The
Shoe court faulted United for offering
"free" repair because this practice bundled United's repair service with its lease.
n60 Yet United could not have used such a tie to exclude an equally efficient
rival. Nothing in the tie prevented the rival from offering service of its own.
At core, the
Shoe holding simply reflects the lament that in some industries large companies may
be better able than small companies to offer the services that customers want.
If antitrust law bans such arrangements, it hurts no one more than the
customers themselves. n61
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n60
110 F. Supp. at 340.
n61
Cf. F. FISHER, J. McGOWAN
& J. GREENWOOD,
supra note 2, at 218 ("IBM's policy of
protecting its own assets by maintaining them itself could not be a barrier to
entry."). On the efficiency reasons for tying service contracts to leasing and sales
contracts, see
infra text accompanying notes 77-81.
We analyze this particular example of tying only, not the more general
controversies in that field. For a discussion of these more general
controversies, see
Jefferson Parish Hosp. Dist. No. 2 v. Hyde, 466 U.S. 2 (1984).
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
4. Differential Rates of Return
Judge Wyzanski ruled that United had excluded competitors by earning rates of
return scaled to the level of competition faced by each of its machines. n62
Yet current law permits a monopolist to charge a monopoly price. It does so
because any ban on monopoly pricing would force courts to become, in effect,
public utility
rate regulators. n63 If charging a monopoly price is legal, however, then the
onus of United's actions lay in
lowering its monopoly price on
[*709] some items to a competitive level. n64 No antitrust rule could be more
perverse than a ban on competitive pricing. n65
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n62
See supra text accompanying note 30.
n63
See
Berkey Photo, Inc. v. Eastman Kodak Co., 603 F.2d 263, 294 (2d Cir. 1979) ("Such judicial oversight of pricing policies would place the courts in a role
akin to that of a public regulatory commission."),
cert. denied,
444 U.S. 1093 (1980).
n64 The accounting and supervision task that judicial review of pricing would
involve is hardly eased because a monopolist earns a variety of different
accounting profits on different products. Holding low prices illegal as
exclusionary
will provide a subsidy to small businesses at the expense of consumer welfare.
But see Peritz,
A Genealogy of Vertical Restraints Doctrine,
40 HASTINGS L.J. 511, 572-74, 576 (1989) (defending small business preservation as an appropriate antitrust goal).
n65 In addition to the four problems just discussed, Judge Wyzanski also
incorrectly analyzed United's
"Right of Deduction Fund" policy. Under this policy, United set aside a small percentage of each
lessee's rent payments for that lessee's Right of Deduction Fund. A lessee that
returned a machine early would otherwise have faced a variety of special
charges. Under this policy, however, the lessee could apply the money in that
Fund toward those charges. Judge Wyzanski concluded that this policy
"deters, though probably only mildly, the opportunities of a competing shoe
manufacturer."
110 F. Supp. at 325. In essence, however, the Fund was nothing more than a quantity discount. As
such, the Fund did deter the opportunities of United competitors. But
discounting always does. That is competition.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
C.
Efficiency Reasons for Leasing
If United did not lease to exclude competitors, why it did lease remains an
issue. A wide variety of explanations present themselves, and we discuss
several of the more prominent: transaction costs, risk-bearing, financing,
incentives for maintenance, and incentives for product quality. n66 None of
these justifies a ban on lease-only policies. Instead, each shows how leasing
often benefits
both the customer and the producer. In fact, it often benefits the
[*710] parties so extensively that neither has any interest in a sale. A lease-only
policy can arise, in short, not because the producer wants to suppress sales,
but because no customer wants to buy. The
Shoe case apparently presented just this situation, given the complete absence of
customer protest about leasing. n67
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n66 Judge Wyzanski's opinion shows that he understood (however
unenthusiastically) many of these efficiency reasons for leasing:
It has been easy for a person with modest capital and of something less than
superior efficiency to become a shoe manufacturer. He can get machines without
buying them; his machines are serviced without separate charges; he can
conveniently exchange an older United model for a new United model; he can
change from one process to another . . . .
110 F. Supp. at 323.
The court also found that
"leasing has been traditional in the shoe machinery field since the Civil War.
So far as this record indicates, there is virtually no expressed
dissatisfaction from consumers respecting that system; and Compo, United's
principal
competitor, endorses and uses it."
Id. at 340. The court also pointed out:
[A] large number of shoe manufacturers . . . expressed their preference for
leasing rather than buying machines. How deeply rooted is this preference might
be disputed; but it cannot be denied that virtually all the shoe manufacturers
who took the stand, and the 45 shoe manufacturers who were selected as a sample
by the Court, expressed a preference for the leasing system.
Id. at 349. That Judge Wyzanski insisted on a
"sample" of 45 more consumer witnesses suggests that his regard for the value of
leasing did not come swiftly. Nor did his opinion fully recount United's more
elaborate and compelling efficiency defense. C. KAYSEN,
supra note 16, at 190-91;
see also id. at 202 ("As seen by the shoe manufacturer, United's activities are clearly benevolent.").
n67
See C. KAYSEN,
supra note
16, at 278 ("The testimony of the shoe manufacturers indicates unequivocally that they do
not now desire a sales system.");
supra note 66.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
1. Transaction Costs
Most importantly, leasing can reduce transaction costs. A short-term user's
alternative to leasing is to purchase: to buy the product, use it for a short
time, and then resell it. In a world without transaction costs, business
travelers would be willing to buy cars at their destinations and resell them
there the next day. We do not see this behavior because it is prohibitively
expensive: Each traveler would have to find a car seller, arrange
transportation to meet the seller, determine car quality, register ownership,
pay sales tax, buy auto insurance -- and then repeat the transaction the next
day as the seller. The costs to a car rental agency for the equivalent rental
transaction are trivial by
comparison. Even if it is a monopolist, the agency can offer a rental service
that travelers would prefer to the prospect of enmeshing transactions. n68
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n68 Bankruptcy costs, a special form of transaction costs, also may provide a
reason to lease rather than to sell. Victor Goldberg has suggested that leasing
expedites the reallocation of resources in the event the user of the product
declares bankruptcy. If bankruptcy law speeds the redeployment of assets that
are leased rather than sold, the prospect of this profitable recovery and reuse
of the asset could decrease United Shoe Machinery's willingness to sell, thus
leading to a lease even when the customer was indifferent about the form of the
transaction. V. Goldberg, The United Shoe Machinery Leases 11-13 (unpublished
manuscript). Consistent with Goldberg's suggestion, United's standard lease did
give it the right to terminate forthwith in the event a lessee became insolvent
or bankrupt,
in which case the lessee was obligated to return the machine to United in
Massachusetts. 110 F. Supp. at 317-18. We remain unsure, however, how much force to ascribe to Goldberg's suggestion.
It appears that bankruptcy law privileges leasing over chattel mortgage sales
only in insignificant ways, and that this difference does not create any
standard preference for leasing among bankruptcy lawyers. Moreover, a concern
with bankruptcy recovery does not seem to explain particular features of the
United leases that the government repeatedly attacked, while a great number of
other possible efficiencies can account for United's general interest in
leasing.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
2. Risk Allocation
Risk allocation also often accounts for leasing. Suppose that a small business,
Smithco, decides that it needs a computer given the present level of sales, but
that
sales might decline. If Smithco buys
[*711] the computer, it bears the risk that future sales indeed will decline and that
the computer will go unused. If it leases the computer, it can shift that risk
to IBM. If the producer can more cheaply diversify the risk than the user,
leasing is efficient. n69 Special provisions of the lease can shift the risk
still further. By making its lessee's monthly rental charge largely contingent
on the number of shoes made with the machines, United's leases did just that.
n70
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n69
See F. FISHER, J. McGOWAN
& J. GREENWOOD,
supra note 2, at 191-93 (discussing differences in allocation of risk in computer
lease and sale transactions);
see also
United Shoe, 222 F. at 391 (lessees of United's machinery
"cannot be supposed desirous of surrendering" the advantage
"of paying for the privilege of their use only
according to the amount of use").
n70 If shoe demand is low, few shoes are made, and the total rental fee is low.
If the entire fee were a flat monthly payment, on the other hand, the renter
would have just as high payments in bad times as in good. The form of the lease
acts as partial insurance against low demand for shoes.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
The parties can also use leases to allocate a variety of other risks between
producer and user. The risk of technological obsolescence is one such risk. n71
United's leases reflected a variety of others. The company charged its lessees
four fees: (a) a monthly rental, (b) a payment per pair of shoes made with the
machine (with a flat minimum if too few shoes were made), (c) a payment upon
termination or expiration of the lease, and (d) a payment
in case of loss by fire or accident. n72 Under charge (d), the lessee did bear
part of the loss in case of fire -- presumably to give some incentive to smoke
carefully and to extinguish fires. But the lease acted like fire insurance with
a deductible; the lease stated that the charge was only
"partial reimbursement . . . for such destruction, and the lessee [was required]
forthwith [to] return whatever remain[ed] of the machinery so destroyed to the
United Corporation at Beverly, Massachusetts." n73 Moreover, by requiring the return of the machine's wreckage to verify
loss, United could eliminate a lessee's incentive to avoid future lease
payments by paying $ 200 and claiming total loss of a usable machine. True, had
the customer bought the machine instead of leasing it, it could have bought its
own separate
[*712] fire insurance. Yet given the ease with which insured parties can file
fraudulent claims on
movable machinery, insurance for its loss might be more expensive. n74 Leasing
may have provided that insurance more cheaply.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n71
Compare F. FISHER, J. McGOWAN
& J. GREENWOOD,
supra note 2, at 191-92
& n.16 (competitive pressure forced IBM to reject its treasurer's 1964
suggestion that IBM refuse to rent any System/360 equipment so as to place risk
of technological obsolescence on customers)
with Carroll,
Hurt by a Pricing War, IBM Plans Write-Off and Cut of 10,000 Jobs, Wall St. J., Dec. 6, 1989, at A1, col. 6 ("That security blanket unraveled in the 1970s as technology began moving so fast
that IBM decided it had to start selling machines, lest its rental equipment
suddenly become obsolete overnight.").
n72
110 F. Supp. at 314-18.
n73
Id. at 315-16. The fire-loss payment for a typical machine was $ 200, which is low compared
with the minimum yearly rent of $ 87 and the expiration payment of $ 75.
Id. at 314.
n74 United was in a better position to avoid such fraud because of its
extensive knowledge of its customers' operations.
See infra note 77; C. KAYSEN,
supra note 16, at 23, 29, 47-50. United's
"Outside Machine Installation Reports" tracked customers' use of rival machines
"with all the attention a doting mother devotes to an only child."
Id. at 114.
United had once required lessees to obtain insurance for its machines but for
25 years had waived the requirement.
110 F. Supp. at 321-22.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
3. Financing
When producers can raise capital more cheaply than their customers, financing
considerations can also cause them to
lease. Suppose that neither IBM nor Smithco has present cash for the computer
-- IBM must borrow to produce it, and Smithco must borrow to buy it. If Smithco
buys the computer, IBM can use the sales price to retire its loan, but
Smithco's loan will remain outstanding. If Smithco leases the computer, IBM
must continue its loan, but Smithco can simply pay an annual rental charge out
of its revenue. If IBM, being a bigger and better known company, can borrow
more cheaply than Smithco, then leasing is more efficient. In effect, IBM plays
banker to Smithco; the arrangement makes sense because IBM, by monitoring the
use of the leased machine, may know more about Smithco's business health than a
bank would. n75
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n75 The use of leasing to replace borrowing is a standard chapter in
finance texts.
See R. BREALEY
& S. MYERS, PRINCIPLES OF CORPORATE FINANCE 521-45 (1981); T. COPELAND
& J.F. WESTON, FINANCIAL THEORY AND CORPORATE POLICY 536-58 (2d ed. 1983). This
is consistent with the 1917
Shoe opinion:
The testimony also shows that the advantage of the leases was and is that
manufacturers of not large means were able to obtain machinery which they were
without capital to buy. They helped, indeed, the big and the little. One
manufacturer whose output was 5,000 pairs of shoes a day testified that if his
company had been compelled to buy outright the machinery necessary to equip its
factory, it could not have developed as it had.
247 U.S. at 63;
see also
222 F. at 352 (leasing
"enabled manufacturers of small and moderate means to embark in manufacturing to
an extent which would have been impossible for them, if they had been obliged
to purchase machinery, because many machines are so expensive as to lock up
capital and render it dead for practical purposes of
financing shoe manufacturing."); Carroll,
supra note 71, at A8, col. 1 ("Because IBM can borrow more cheaply than its much smaller rivals, it can offer
customers very attractive leasing deals.").
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
[*713] 4. Maintenance
In markets for durable goods, maintenance considerations can also cause the
parties to lease. For complicated equipment like shoe machinery, the producer
will often be the party best able to service the machine. Frequently, however,
the producer and customer face a classic
"moral hazard" problem: Customers buying repair services on a per-problem basis give the
producer an incentive to charge a high price and fix only the symptoms of the
problem. n76
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n76 On moral hazard issues generally, see E. RASMUSEN,
supra note 7, at chs. 6
& 7. The problem is most acute
in durable-goods markets because customers are less likely to return to the
producer for repeat purchases. Hence, reputation considerations are less likely
to eliminate the moral hazard problem described in this Section.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
By leasing the machine, the parties can reduce this moral hazard. The price of
the repairs will no longer be an issue, and the lessor will have an incentive
to fix the machine properly. In fact, if the rental charge increases with use
(as in
Shoe), the lessor also will want to fix it promptly. n77 Although the lessee has
less incentive to maintain the product, the lessor can reserve its right to
check maintenance and look for abuse. n78
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n77
See
110 F. Supp. at 302 ("And breakdowns of such machines should be promptly attended to, because, in the
shoe manufacturing industry, stoppages are particularly costly.");
id. at 322 ("Calls for this service [repairing breakdowns] are
frequent: in some factories 2 to 10 men are needed every day.");
id. ("In all respects, the service rendered by United is uniformly of excellent
quality. It is promptly, efficiently, and courteously rendered.");
see also
247 U.S. at 56 (1918
Shoe decision speaks glowingly of
"a service force . . . estimated at 6,000 men, to repair immediately breaks or
deterioration without extra charge. And these men are kept at convenient places
to repair machines and replace worn-out parts, and depots of supplies are
maintained.");
id. at 64 ("The breakdown of some of these machines will in many of the factories block the
entire flow of the work.") (quoting testimony of United's president).
n78 The United lease did so provide.
110 F. Supp. at 315. Note, too, that the court stated,
"In fact, United has at all times assumed the burden of keeping its leased
machinery in good order. It has made no separate
charge to the lessee for such services, but has charged him for such parts as
are required."
Id. at 322. It is, in fact, much easier for customers to know that they have received new
parts than proper service.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
The parties also would have eliminated much of this moral hazard problem if the
consumers could have bought service contracts in a competitive market for
maintenance services. Judge Wyzanski apparently had this in mind when he
ordered United to charge separately for service. n79 In the process, however,
he was likely to have created the opposite moral hazard problem: Customers
[*714] who can pay separately for the service contract gain an incentive to buy one
of inefficiently low quality. True, customers have some incentive to buy a
service contract of high quality because poor quality service will reduce their
output and profit. Yet because customers pay rental fees based on output, part
of the
loss from poor quality repairs would fall on United. As a result of Judge
Wyzanski's order, the lessee paid the full cost of repair under the service
contract but shared with United the resulting benefits. It is possible that
customers thereby gained the incentive to keep repair expenses at inefficiently
low levels. Bundling the lease with the service contract can eliminate this
problem by implicitly letting United and its customer split the cost of the
service contract. Forced to unbundle its services and leasing, however, United
was now less likely to offer the output-based leasing that its customers
enjoyed. n80
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n79 The court's goal was the development of large independent repair companies,
which in turn would free United's competitors from the need to offer service
with their machines.
See
110 F. Supp. at 325. The court conceded, however, that
"no [service] system that has been suggested would be likely to be superior from
a technological viewpoint. Shoe
manufacturers, in general, are well satisfied with the technical service."
Id. at 322. The court thus seemed more interested in rivalry than efficiency.
n80
Cf. C. KAYSEN,
supra note 16, at 190 ("Since United is paid on performance, including high rate of output and
dependability of production, the design of rugged, high performance machines is
stimulated.").
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
This analysis is not exhaustive. One can reply, for instance, that United could
have double-checked the quality of another firm's service by direct inspection.
n81 A problem with judicially engineered
"less restrictive alternatives," however, is that they are not always less expensive; in fact, the judge will
have out-managed the company if they are. Some doubt judges' capacity on this
score. Rather than exhaust this question, however, our aims here are simpler:
to underline the complexity of principal-agent relations that lurk within
apparently simple tasks like maintenance and to
stress the consequent attraction of allowing firms the flexibility to adopt and
adapt arrangements like leasing to cope with such complexities.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n81
See supra note 78 and accompanying text.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
5. Product Quality
The unobservability of product quality in some markets can also cause parties
to lease. Suppose that (a) customers cannot determine quality until after they
have bought the product, and (b) low quality is cheaper to produce than high
quality. In markets of this sort, sellers will often produce only low quality,
and customers will only pay a low price. For nondurable goods, this problem
need not be severe -- the seller may decide to produce high quality at the
outset to preserve its reputation and to charge a high price in the future. n82
[*715] But in a durable-goods market, customers do not
return for new purchases, and the seller has a lessened incentive to maintain
its reputation.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n82 This argument is spelled out in Klein
& Leffler,
The Role of Market Forces in Assuring Contractual Performance, 89 J. POL. ECON. 615 (1981);
see id. at 620. For a shorter explanation, see E. RASMUSEN,
supra note 7, at 96-99.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
Nonetheless, by leasing instead of selling, producers in these markets sustain
an incentive to maintain product quality and firm reputation. Under leasing,
customers make payments at regular intervals. They thus know that if a producer
cheats them with low quality once, they can refuse to pay a high price
thereafter, and that this threat can keep the producer honest. n83
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n83 This argument, unlike the Coase Conjecture, does not rely on different
customers having
different valuations of the product. But both arguments focus on the ability of
a lease to transform a single long-term market into a series of short-term
ones. Again, unlike the Coase Conjecture, the quality argument applies to both
competitive and monopolized markets, and it implies that leasing can be good
for both suppliers (who get higher prices) and customers (who get higher
quality).
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
* * * *
These explanations show how leasing can be efficient -- indeed, extremely
valuable. n84 Similar considerations may also explain some
[*716] of the more arcane clauses of particular leases. For example, we have
mentioned that the United practice of making the rental charge increase with
heavier use of the machine might have been designed to share risk. Using such a
system of charges also leads, however, to other problems that can complicate
the lease. Judge Wyzanski condemned United for its use of a
"full capacity clause," which gave United the right to cancel the lease and recover the machine unless
"the lessee shall use the leased machinery to its full capacity." n85 Yet United may have merely been trying to prevent customers from using
extra United machines as cheap insurance against the possibility that the
principal machine would break down. In essence, such customers may have been
exploiting United's pay-by-use fee schedule.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n84 This list is far from exhaustive. Particular cases can reveal a host of
other particular efficiency explanations. For example, leasing can make patent
infringement more difficult by making it harder for the purchaser to take the
product apart. The consensus today is that strong enforcement of patents is a
good thing for consumers because it provides a valuable incentive for valuable
innovation. Leasing can also be
used to protect the lead-time monopoly returns on unpatented inventions.
Whether the law ought to facilitate that monopoly pricing is considerably more
controversial.
See generally infra note 120.
Producers also might lease to internalize spillover effects. For example, most
private clubs do not give their members transferable property rights in the
club -- in effect, they lease the use of the club to their members. Were they
to sell, members who transferred their membership to the
"wrong" persons would depreciate the value of membership. Selling a membership to the
future
"club bore" spills over harm to all other members.
Similarly, leasing might aim to protect the capital value of a trademark. The
father of one of the authors once plausibly (or at least illustratively)
claimed that Rolls Royce sold its cars only to those with sufficient social
standing and thus refused sales to some
"undesirables" with the requisite cash. Because the cars were transferable, however, the
scheme soon
broke down. Had it adopted a lease-only policy, the company could have avoided
the problem. Antitrust law accepted a similar justification for tying (rather
than leasing) in
United States v. Jerrold Elec. Corp., 187 F. Supp. 545 (E.D. Pa. 1960),
aff'd per curiam,
365 U.S. 567 (1961) (defendant allowed to tie CATV components and service because cable failures
would have reflected adversely on the infant cable industry).
By placing it in closer contact with those making daily use of its machines,
leasing may also facilitate the lessor's research effort to improve its
product. United claimed this advantage.
See C. KAYSEN,
supra note 16, at 171, 190.
n85
110 F. Supp. at 317. Wyzanski noted that:
Despite its express terms, the full capacity clause is not considered by United
to have been violated
unless the lessee fails to use the machine on work for which the machine is
capable of being used, and instead performs such work by using a competitor's
machine. In other words, it is not treated as a violation if the lessee fails
to use United's machines because he performs the work by hand, or because he
discontinues the type of operation for which the machine is capable of being
used.
Id. at 320;
see also supra note 27 and accompanying text.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
That problem arises precisely because United charged its lessees according to
how heavily they used the machine n86 so that a lessee with low use incurred a
relatively low fee. If a shoe company needed, say, one machine operating at all
times, then United's schedule would tempt lessees to rent two machines: one for
use and one as an emergency backup. If United charged a
flat
rental fee, it would not mind this strategy. But many customers might prefer
the lower risk of a use-sensitive fee. n87 Because United did charge a rental
fee that increased with output, it would be reluctant to offer free insurance
of this kind. In fact, it might not even collect a profitable rent on the
machine in use; the customer could rent a competitor's machine for normal
production and United's machine for a backup. n88
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n86
See supra text accompanying note 72.
n87
See supra note 69 and accompanying text.
n88 A similar story could be told about a customer who wanted to keep one
machine for normal use and an extra machine for
"peak-load" use during periods of extraordinary demand. Sometimes customers legitimately
need extra
machines for this use, and United had special short-term leases for such
customers.
"United's practice is to furnish a machine temporarily and only for a limited
period to take care of periods of peak production in a shoe factory."
110 F. Supp. at 321.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
The full-capacity clause thus may have facilitated a mutually desirable
allocation of risk by preventing opportunistic behavior by
[*717] lessees. n89 Two facts support this efficiency interpretation of the
fullcapacity clause and contradict the usual argument that the clause was
nothing more than United's effort to buy a customer's promise not to deal with
competitors. First, one of United's constituent companies used this lease
clause before the original United merger -- presumably before it gained
monopoly power. n90 But a firm lacking monopoly power has difficulty
insisting on a simple exclusionary promise. Imagine your reaction, for
instance, if a local supermarket demanded your promise that you never buy
groceries from competing grocers. Second, United offered to waive the
fullcapacity clause
"for a 'reasonable time' if a lessee wishes to try out a competitive machine." n91 Willingness to waive the clause in just the situation where its
exclusionary effect would be greatest suggests an exclusionary interpretation
is incorrect.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n89
Compare Klein, Crawford
& Alchian,
Vertical Integration, Appropriable Rents, and the Competitive Contracting
Process,
21 J.L. & ECON. 297, 297-98 (1978)
with O. WILLIAMSON, MARKETS AND HIERARCHIES: ANALYSIS AND ANTITRUST IMPLICATIONS
26-30 (1975).
Two earlier
Shoe courts excused the full-capacity clause with explanations consistent with our
"free insurance" hypothesis.
See
247 U.S. at 62 ("Without [the full-capacity clause] defendants say that as lessors, they would
have no assurance of compensation for their machine.");
222 F. at 389 ("The lessor might well accept for the use of its machine a smaller royalty per
pair, based upon the understanding that the machine would turn out as many
pairs as its capacity permitted, than it could afford to accept without any
such assurance.").
n90
"This clause was in the lease of the Consolidated Company prior to the formation
of the United Company."
247 U.S. at 62.
n91 C. KAYSEN,
supra note 16, at 70.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
D.
Monopoly Reasons for Leasing
These efficiency explanations for leasing have no necessary link with monopoly
although they apply to transactions in monopolized markets as well as in
competitive markets. Antitrust errs if it deters such conduct, whether by a
monopolist or by a competitive firm. In the case of two
other motivations for leasing -- price discrimination and the Coase Conjecture
-- the implications for antitrust policy are not so clear.
1. Price Discrimination
Price discrimination would appeal only to a firm with market power and the
freedom to depart from cost-based pricing. Suppose a monopoly supplier faces
two customers: a highly profitable manufacturer of boots and a marginal maker
of sandals. The monopolist would prefer to charge each its willingness to pay.
A policy of sales,
[*718] however, will not accomplish this goal if the sandal maker can engage in
arbitrage by buying machines low and reselling high to the boot manufacturer.
By leasing rather than selling, the monopolist can retain control over the
machines, prevent arbitrage, and thus succeed in price discrimination. n92
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n92 Victor Goldberg discusses this possibility and concludes that it might
explain United's
lease practice.
See V. Goldberg,
supra note 68, at 6-10. Certainly United's lease policy of charging by the number of
shoes its machines produced,
see supra note 72 and accompanying text, looks like a classic case of price
discrimination -- unless the use charge perfectly mirrored depreciation from
use.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
To note that monopolists may sometimes use leases to price-discriminate,
however, fails to justify
Shoe's ban on lease-only policies. Even if no efficiency reasons supported leasing,
n93 price discrimination alone would not warrant such a ban. Judges could ban
discriminatory leasing without banning all leasing. And notwithstanding the
hostility that many courts have shown toward the practice, n94 it is far from
clear that price discrimination necessarily harms anyone. Instead, a ban could
cause the seller to reduce its
output because it might give up selling to the customers (like the sandal
maker) who pay the low price. An economist's typical conclusion is that
"there may be a useful role for government regulation of discriminatory pricing,
but . . . a flat ban could have adverse welfare consequences." n95 In this Article, therefore, we treat current hostility in antitrust law
toward price discrimination generally as insufficiently justified to support
Shoe's ban on lease-only policies.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n93
But see supra text accompanying notes 66-91.
n94
See
Jefferson Parish Hosp. Dist. No. 2 v. Hyde, 466 U.S. 2, 14-15 & n.23 (1984).
n95 Katz,
The Welfare Effects of Third-Degree Price Discrimination in Intermediate Good
Markets,
77 AM. ECON. REV. 154, 165 (1987). Katz
lists the relevant recent literature, which is based on research from the
1930s.
Id. at 167.
See also Hausman
& MacKie-Mason,
Price Discrimination and Patent Policy, 19 RAND J. ECON. 253 (1988) (generally beneficial to permit price
discrimination by monopolist that gained market power through a patented
innovation); H. HOVENKAMP,
supra note 41;
supra note 69.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
2. The Coase Conjecture
The second motivation for leasing that might require antitrust regulation is
the Coase Conjecture. According to the Conjecture, even if a durable-goods
monopolist cannot charge a monopoly price for its sales, it may be able to do
so through a lease. Because leases enable the producer to sell the nondurable
stream of services generated by the durable good rather than the good itself,
they enable the producer to earn monopoly rents. For all the attention
economists have paid to the Coase Conjecture, however, few lawyers have
[*719] noted its implications for government policy. With their suggestion that Coase
supports
Shoe, Posner and Easterbrook remain among the few who have tried to integrate the
Coase literature into their analysis of antitrust law. n96 As we shall see,
however, Coase's logic supports the
Shoe rule only in a quite modified form -- if at all.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n96
See supra note 14 and accompanying text.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
III. FITTING
SHOE TO COASE'S LAST
By Coase's logic, the monopolist can use a lease to obtain a monopoly instead
of a competitive return -- an antitrust evil. n97 Consequently, the
Shoe rule seems like sensible industrial policy. In fact, however, Coase's logic
dictates a rule broader in some respects and narrower in others than the one in
Shoe.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n97
See supra note 51.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
A.
Broadening the Shoe
Rule
United Shoe Machinery leased and did not sell its most important machines. As a
remedy to this supposedly bad conduct, the court ordered it merely to
supplement -- not replace -- its leasing policy with a sales option. n98
Apparently, the firm could have escaped liability by offering the sales option
in the first place.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n98
110 F. Supp. at 349-51.
Kaysen had recommended that
"United should be enjoined from marketing machines by any other method than sale." C. KAYSEN,
supra note 16, at 275. But Judge Wyzanski decided otherwise after he read his wife
his 100-plus page draft opinion, and he found himself unable to answer her
question,
"But why, if the terms are economically equivalent, shouldn't a customer, if he
wants to lease, be able to lease?"
See
Wyzanski,
John A. Sibley Lecture -- An Activist Judge: Mea Maxima Culpa. Apologia Pro
Vita Mea.,
7 GA. L. REV. 202, 213 (1973).
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
According to the Coase story, however, a sales option ought not to rescue a
lease option so long as a significant number of consumers actually lease rather
than buy. n99 The crucial element of a monopoly-enhancing lease is that the
monopolist has an incentive to maintain high prices in the future. If a
significant number of highvaluation consumers lease rather than buy, the
monopolist does retain this incentive. For if the monopolist cuts its sales
price in the future, the high-valuation customers who lease at the high price
will cancel their leases and buy at the low price. The high-priced leases thus
guard against future sales discounts and eliminate the incentive for the high-valuation customers to withhold present patronage.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n99 In this respect the 1922 Supreme Court
Shoe rule is more in accord with Coase's logic than is Judge Wyzanski's opinion.
See supra note 20.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
[*720] Thus, Judge Wyzanski's remedy of requiring a sales option is an ineffective
cure to the problem that Coase explained. Instead, Coase's logic dictates a
broader remedy: a complete ban on leasing. Forced to sell and sell alone, the
monopolist will be unable to charge its monopoly price.
This point has two implications, one soothing and one troubling. The soothing
implication is that this broader remedy would save courts from having to
specify exactly what price the monopolist ought to charge when it sells. A
court requiring the company to sell
and lease must say something about its relative prices. Otherwise the monopolist
can simply charge a sales
price so high that all consumers continue leasing. For the court, the obvious
choice of sales price is the capitalized value of the monopoly rental charge.
Even at that price, however, consumers would still prefer to lease. For as
Coase described, if many consumers were to buy at this high price, their action
would tempt the monopolist to lower the sales price in order to sell to
lower-valuation buyers. When that occurred, the buyers would suffer a capital
loss, but the lessees would not. Lest they suffer that capital loss, consumers
would lease. Ironically, because all other consumers make the same choice and
lease, the consumer who leases thereby helps ensure that the monopolist will
continue to charge monopoly prices. Thus to ensure that any significant number
of customers bought, the court would have to order that the sales price be
more attractive than the lease price -- just what the government requested, and the
court refused in the
Shoe case. n100
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n100
110 F. Supp. at 350.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
Ultimately, setting an appropriate sales price is not the sort of issue courts
determine well. Even calculating the capitalized value of the rental charge may
require more information than a court will have. And we have just shown that to
make any difference, the sales price must be lower than this capitalized value.
Deciding how much lower is the kind of question public utility commissions
spend months deciding in rate-of-return hearings. Judge Wyzanski foresaw some
of these administrative problems and responded with simple and unsatisfying
bluster. n101 A simpler response -- with greater logical integrity -- would
have been a complete ban on leasing.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n101
See
id. at 351;
see also
id. at 349 (similar relief impossible
"without turning United into a public utility, and the Court into a public
utility commission"); C. KAYSEN,
supra note
16, at 271-72, 277.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
The troubling implication of a sales-only rule is the perverse incentive it
creates for the monopolist. Courts that ban leasing may
[*721] encourage the monopolist to engage in planned obsolescence by making goods
less durable. n102 Courts heeding Coase thus must act more boldly than did
Judge Wyzanski, but this boldness will simplify some matters only by inevitably
complicating others.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n102
See supra note 7 and accompanying text;
but cf. Malueg
& Solow,
On Requiring the Durable Goods Monopolist To Sell, 25 ECON. LETTERS 283 (1987) (simplified model tentatively suggests that a
policy of requiring sales more often will lead to beneficial than to harmful
effects).
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
B.
Five Limits on Coase's Logic
Coase's logical support for the
Shoe rule also bounds it. His explanation is the exceptional case; it does not
explain why, for example, firms lease short-term services: why Hertz rents cars
or Sheraton rents rooms. Neither does it explain why firms lease durable goods
in competitive markets. A firm trying to lease such a good at a high price
would simply lose customers. It does not even explain why they lease in
monopolized markets if, before introducing the lease-only policy, a firm had
sold enough goods outright that it faces competition from its past customers.
n103 But even if a good is durable and the seller a genuine monopolist, the
following five qualifications show that a rule founded on Coase's justification
would have to be focused still further. Indeed, they show that its proper range
of concern not only excludes the facts of the
Shoe case, but is in fact too
narrow and intractable for courts to worry about at all.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n103 Competition from past customers is likely when the merger of existing
sellers created the monopoly power. This competition can make mergers in such
markets of less concern than otherwise.
See Carlton
& Gertner,
supra note 3.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
1. Leasing is Innocuous When Demand is Constant
Coase and most later researchers n104 discussed the Conjecture in the context
of markets with a fixed number of buyers. Yet such lumpy markets are scarce.
The more usual case is one where new consumers regularly enter the market. A
stream of new consumers, however, makes the Conjecture irrelevant. n105
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n104 With the exception of Conlisk, Gerstner
& Sobel,
Cyclic Pricing by a Durable Goods Monopolist, 99 Q.J. ECON. 489 (1984).
n105 The applicability of the Coase Conjecture is limited if
"durable" goods
eventually give rise to replacement sales.
See Bond
& Samuelson,
supra note 8; Gul, Sonnenschein
& Wilson,
supra note 6; Suslow,
supra note 9. In addition, the prospect of repeat sales may eliminate the viability
of the Coase Conjecture.
See Gaskins,
Alcoa Revisited: The Welfare Implications of a Secondhand Market, 7 J. ECON. THEORY 254 (1974); Gul, Sonnenschein
& Wilson,
supra note 6.
This discussion assumes that the Low purchasers do not remain potential buyers
forever. If they do, then the Lows will
"pile up," and the seller may find it profitable to hold periodic discount sales.
See generally Conlisk, Gerstner
& Sobel,
supra note 104. This strategy would work only if a large number of Highs did not
anticipate this sale and found it profitable to withhold their purchases at the
high price. To the extent that they wait for the
discount sales, the Coasian dilemma reappears.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
[*722] To understand why the Conjecture plays no role in markets with new consumers,
consider once again its logic. The monopolist would like to sell its durable
goods to the Highs at a high price. As soon as it did so, though, it would have
an incentive to lower its price and sell to the Lows. Because the Highs
recognize this temptation, they wait for the discount sale and refuse to pay
the initial high price. Rather than wait forever for the Highs to buy, the
monopolist discounts the goods from the outset.
Fortunately for the monopolist and unfortunately for the public, this logic
self-destructs if new consumers regularly enter the market. Suppose that new
High and Low buyers appear regularly. If the monopolist were to use the Coasian
price discrimination strategy (pick off the initial Highs at a high price, then
sell cheaply to the Lows), it necessarily would also sell cheaply to the Highs
who appeared
later. The monopolist can sell to the initial-period Lows only by lowering the
price, and if it lowers the price, it abandons the monopoly rents it would
otherwise earn by charging a high price to the later Highs.
As a result, a durable-goods monopolist in a dynamic market will price its
products by comparing the profits from more sales at a lower price with those
from fewer sales at a higher price. It will price low at the outset only if (a)
the present value of its future profits from selling at marginal cost to many
buyers (both Highs and Lows) exceeds (b) the present value of its monopoly rents from
selling at a higher price to fewer buyers (only Highs). Readers will recognize
that tradeoff, however, as the standard tradeoff all monopolists face.
Consequently, if new buyers regularly enter and leave the market for a
durable good, they transform the durable-goods monopolist's otherwise peculiar
position into exactly the one all other monopolists face. Suppose the
durable-goods monopolist sells in a market where the same mix of High and Low
buyers appears each year, and buyers disappear if they do not buy. If --
following Coase -- the monopolist would prefer to sell fewer goods at a higher
price in year 1, it necessarily will prefer the same strategy in each of the
later years. If so, however, its threat to maintain high prices in subsequent
years becomes credible. With that credibility, the Coase Conjecture
disintegrates: if the monopolist loses by lowering its price after the initial
Highs buy, those Highs gain nothing by waiting;
[*723] accordingly, if the monopolist charges a high price from the start, the Highs
will pay.
At root, the Coase Conjecture is an artifact of a model where new
buyers fail to appear after year 1. That model may fit an economy that never
grows. In economies that do grow, however, new manufacturers regularly buy
durable equipment. Considerations of business cycles aside, the demand for
equipment stays relatively constant. Suppose, therefore, that a producer
monopolizes the market for a durable machine. Because of the steady queue of
new buyers, the Coase Conjecture would not prevent selling the machines
(notwithstanding their durability) at monopoly prices. Absent any pent-up
demand for the equipment, the producer will face the same number of Highs in
years 2 and 3 as in year 1. Necessarily, if it paid to hold prices high in year
1, it will pay in years 2, 3, and so forth. Everyone would have accepted the
monopolist's threat to keep prices high after the year 1 Highs have bought, and
the
Coasian dilemma will disappear.
If the Coase Conjecture ever did describe a market, it probably describes one
shaped by radical technological innovation. Recall that the Conjecture applies
only if substantially more buyers appear in year 1 than in later years. That
situation generally occurs only in new markets, and new markets generally
emerge only as a result of technological change. For reasons we explain in the
next Section, however, those industries where technological change creates an
unusually large initial demand for a product are often precisely the industries
where the goods rapidly become obsolete -- and Coase's point does not apply.
More generally, the point is this: With truly durable goods, demand is likely
level; with lumpy one-period demand, the goods are seldom durable. The Coase
situation is thus the exception rather than the rule. A sensible part of a
plaintiff's case against a lease-only policy, therefore, would be proof that
the market at issue fulfills the exceptional requirements of the Coase
Conjecture: at the time they executed the leases in question, a one-time demand
existed that the defendant and its customers did not expect would continue.
Absent any evidence of this lumpy demand, courts ought to leave such behavior
alone; absent any evidence of radically lumpy demand for shoe-making machines,
the
Shoe court should have left United alone. n106
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n106
But see
110 F. Supp. at 343;
accord, Kaysen,
Foreword to F. FISHER, J. McGOWAN
& J. GREENWOOD,
supra note 2, at xi (United's market was
"nearly static").
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
[*724] 2. Leasing is Innocuous if Products are Not Durable
At least two reasons exist why high-valuation consumers will often repeat their
purchases through time:
Either the item is not physically durable, or changing technology or tastes
make the physically rugged thing obsolete.
a. Physical durability
No one leases carrots, matches, or listening live to a violinist. No one can.
If the good is not durable at all, use consumes it and makes a sale inevitable.
But even if a good is
"somewhat but not very durable," then Coase's explanation does not apply. Consider beach towels and mats, which
committed beachgoers can wear out quickly. Renting could not raise monopolist
profits very much for a Santa Monica beach monopolist because beach fanatics
(the consumers with a high valuation) soon will be back in the market. So some
reason other than Coase's must motivate a monopolist that leases a somewhat but
not very durable good. n107
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n107 For the
beach mat example, convenience would be the obvious reason why occasional beach
users rent rather than buy a beach mat at dawn and try to resell it over happy
hour margaritas.
See supra text accompanying note 68.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
b. Economic durability
Advancing technology can turn even physically durable goods into economic
perishables. For this reason, no defendant should be condemned for leasing an
apparently durable good if the item's economic life is short. Consider slide
rules. As recently as 1972, these sturdy gadgets promised to last engineers a
lifetime. But indestructibility does not a durable good make. Within a year,
the market for slide rules disappeared. The calculators that replaced the slide
rules in 1973 promised engineers savings in time and accuracy, and engineers
eagerly paid $ 150 and
up for machines that did no more than simple arithmetic. Big and solid, these
machines seemed almost as enduring as their sleek and sliding predecessors.
Once again, though, the machines were far less durable than they seemed.
Technological change soon made these machines obsolete, and within a few years
they were abandoned for the thirty-function, $ 30 programmables.
We ordinarily think of innovation in the context of better machinery in high
tech industries. The principle, however, is the same for
"soft" innovations like new songs or new car shapes. For such soft innovations, the
producer has a monopoly on the new product,
[*725] but only for a very short time before a still newer product enters the market.
Hence, if perchance a creative agency leased rather than sold its short-lived
musical or design creations, it is unlikely to be due to the reason Coase gives.
So
antitrust ought not apply the
Shoe rule in markets where physically robust goods in fact have short economic
lives. This factor would not appear to affect the
Shoe case, in which there were
"no sudden changes in the style of machines." n108 But it qualifies the sweep of the rule in a way that Judge Wyzanski did
not suggest. n109
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n108
110 F. Supp. at 343;
accord Kaysen,
Foreword to F. FISHER, J. McGOWAN
& J. GREENWOOD,
supra note 2, at xi (United's market was
"nearly static" and
"showed only modest technical progress" during a period of nearly thirty years); C. KAYSEN,
supra note 16, at 184 ("Progress in shoe machinery has not been made by leaps and bounds; rather it is
glacial in its character.").
But see
United Shoe, 222 F. at 360 (United claimed its current machines made obsolete the models of 1899).
n109 One perhaps might object that this discussion assumes that technological
change, like time, is impassively inevitable. In truth, of course, it is not --
a monopolist may have the power to control the pace of innovation. Yet this
fact leads to ambiguous policy conclusions. According to Swan, a monopolist
that can commit to future prices or that can lease will innovate at an
efficient rate.
See Swan,
Optimum Durability, Second-Hand Markets, and Planned Obsolescence, 80 J. POL. ECON. 575 (1972). Hence, permitting a durable-goods monopolist to
lease may ensure that the monopolist does not inefficiently alter the pace of
technological change; unfortunately, if the Coase Conjecture applies, it does
so at the cost of monopoly pricing. On the other hand, a monopolist that cannot
lease (one subject to the
Shoe
rule) faces a distorting incentive to change products routinely in order to
transform durable into less durable goods. As a result, if one cost of
permitting durable-goods leasing is monopoly pricing, one cost of banning it
may be planned obsolescence.
Cf. Bulow,
Monopolists, supra note 7 (if the Coase Conjecture held, a monopolist would plan obsolescence for
its products to transform otherwise durable goods into perishable ones); Bulow,
Planned Obsolescence, supra note 7 (same).
In theory, judges could review innovation by monopolists to see if it resulted
from this inefficient desire to realize monopoly profits from durables. But
antitrust in general has been extremely chary of regulating innovation, for
fear of mistaking good innovation for bad and thereby dampening the process
that Schumpeter praised and that has gained particular national prestige in the
last decade.
See
Berkey Photo, Inc. v. Eastman Kodak Co., 603 F.2d 263 (2d Cir. 1979),
cert. denied,
444 U.S. 1093 (1980); Sidak,
Debunking Predatory Innovation,
83 COLUM. L. REV. 1121 (1983). As a result, amplifying the
Shoe ban on lease-only monopoly with an additional ban on
"inefficient" technological change is not likely to be a satisfactory solution to the Coase
problem.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
3. Leasing is Innocuous if Terms are Long
Coase pointed out that his logic dictates that the monopolist adopt
short-term leases. n110 Short-term leases insure that the monopolist's intent to
maintain a high rental charge is credible. If the monopolist uses a one-month
lease and then increases output and
[*726] drives down the price, it will suffer the consequences a month later when it
tries to renew the
leases. If the lease has a ten-year term, then the monopolist has locked in the
lease charge for ten years and has much more incentive to flood the market
after the lease is signed. A hundred-year lease is nearly an outright sale.
Leasing avoids the Coase Conjecture only if it reduces the monopolist's
temptation to increase output and thereby convinces customers that output will
remain low (and prices high). Thus, from the point of view of the Coase
Conjecture, leasing works best when the term of the lease is very short and
best of all when the customer can cancel the lease at any time. n111
Consequently, antitrust should discount the Coase Conjecture as an explanation
of -- and reason to condemn -- leases that are long.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n110 Coase,
supra note 3, at 145 ("Another way in which essentially the same result could be obtained would be for
the landowner not to sell the land but to lease it for
relatively short periods of time.") (emphasis added).
n111 The point that the Coase Conjecture depends on the time interval between
price changes (and, thus, on the term of leases) is developed in detail in
Stokey,
supra note 10.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
In the context of
Shoe, this point is vital. The
Shoe court complained pointedly about the long term of United's ten-year leases.
n112 The case also makes clear, however, that United's customers desired that
long term. Before its antitrust challenges, United usually leased its machines
for seventeen-year terms. After an initial federal challenge, United shortened
this term to seven years.
At its customers' requests, however, it lengthened this term to ten years. n113
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n112
110 F. Supp. at 324 ("The 10-year term is a long commitment.");
see also
id. at 340, 343-44.
n113
Id. at 319.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
There are many efficiency
reasons why suppliers and customers may prefer their relation to be on a
long-term rather than a short-term basis. To guarantee a set price or the
assured availability and quality of perishable goods, customers commonly enter
long-term contracts with sellers willing to trade a price break for a
predictable market. n114 Customers and suppliers of durable goods can likewise
opt for a long-term lease when other considerations n115 lead them to reject an
outright sale. Thus, the demand of United's customers for leases with long
terms is unremarkable --
unless one entertains Coase's explanation for United's leasing.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n114 For listings and discussion of the relevant literature, see Goldberg
& Erickson,
Quantity and Price Adjustment in Long-Term Contracts: A Case Study of Petroleum
Coke,
30 J.L. & ECON. 369 (1987); Joskow,
Price Adjustment in Long-Term Contracts: The Case of Coal,
31 J.L. & ECON. 47 (1988); Polinsky,
Fixed Price vs. Spot Price Contracts: A Study in Risk Allocation, 3 J.L. ECON.
& ORG'N 27 (1987).
n115
See supra notes 66-91 and accompanying text.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
These facts of the case contradict the Coase account if we assume that United
would never consent to customers' requests that
[*727] eliminated its monopoly profit. Instead, United should have wanted a
short-term lease to convince its customers that it would not flood the market at
discount prices. Conversely, if the customers wanted cheaper machines and
somehow succeeded in forcing United to give them long leases, then United would
have been forced
"in the twinkling of an eye" to lower its prices. n116
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n116 Victor Goldberg also infers from the length of the leases that the
Coase Conjecture is not a plausible explanation of United's leasing policy.
See V. Goldberg,
supra note 68, at 3-4.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
As a result, were the Coase Conjecture at work, the
Shoe remedy would be completely backwards. The court ordered that the lease term be
cut in half. n117 If Coase's explanation applied, this remedy would have
enhanced rather than destroyed the monopolist's ability to charge a monopoly
price. Moreover, this part of the remedy also contradicts the court's
insistence that United offer its machines for sale. Because a sale is simply an
infinitely long lease, the court, in effect, told United Shoe that it could
have short-term leases and infinite-term leases but nothing in between. This
remedy could accomplish nothing but consumer injury.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n117
110 F. Supp. at 349, 352. Other provisions of the court remedy effectively
may have reduced the lease term to one year.
See
id. at 352.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
4. Leasing is Innocuous When a Monopolist Could Engage in Static Price
Discrimination
Suppose a monopolist has a mechanism besides leasing that enables it to engage
in static price discrimination: it can simultaneously charge different
consumers according to their differing willingnesses to pay. If the monopolist
also chooses to lease, Coase's explanation cannot be the reason why. A
monopolist engaged in present and effective price discrimination sells to the
Lows at a discount price today. It has no reason to cut prices tomorrow. The
Highs thus have no reason to delay purchases. Coase's explanation cannot be the
reason that such a monopolist leases, and antitrust should not intrude.
Recall our earlier example about the marginal sandal maker and the profitable
boot manufacturer. n118 If United faces only these two customers, it
can stop the arbitrage that defeats its price discrimination scheme by altering
the basic machine so that one version can make only sandals and the other
version only boots. In this way, it can charge a high price to the boot
manufacturer and a low price to the sandal maker without fear that the latter
will resell
[*728] machines to the former. But this accomplishment of static price discrimination
erases United's problem with sustaining a high price to the boot manufacturer.
If United still leases, the reason must not be Coase's.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n118
See supra text accompanying note 92.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
It would be sensible for antitrust to intrude if a durable-goods monopolist
relied upon leasing as its
only way to price-discriminate, were this easily done. We say this despite our
earlier observation n119 that there exists no theoretical warrant generally to
ban all leasing that aims to accomplish price discrimination. Suppose the
monopolist must lease to implement static price discrimination (perhaps because
it must meter use of the product). By this assumption, the monopolist must
lease to discriminate between users; without leasing, it will have no
alternative other than to sell at a single price. Yet the monopolist will face
the problem that Coase describes if it sells at a single price. In this
situation, then, antitrust can force the price down to the competitive level by
banning leasing. This result contrasts with the usual effect of banning price
discrimination which is a single price at the monopoly level. Whether the move
from price discrimination to a monopoly price is good is unclear, but the move
to a competitive price is indisputably good. Hence, if leasing is necessary to
price-discriminate in the market for a durable good, the use of price
discrimination should be
no excuse for leasing.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n119
See supra note 95 and accompanying text.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
Especially when so qualified, this fourth limitation sweeps less broadly than
the previous three. Effective price discrimination is generally difficult and
therefore not the norm because a monopolist can rarely prevent the arbitrage
that creates a nondiscriminatory secondary market. Nonetheless, institutional
peculiarities sometimes do permit sellers with some market power to employ
price discrimination. If a firm leases in these situations, Coase's explanation
is not the right one. Antitrust again should stay its hand.
5. Leasing is Innocuous When Patents Entitle a Monopolist to Its Monopoly Profit
Patents are legal monopolies designed to encourage innovation by allowing the
innovator a price above production cost. The premise behind patent law is that
the reward of monopoly power is appropriate because consumers would have no
surplus at all had the
inventor not created the innovation in the first place. But the Coase
Conjecture shows that without leasing, an innovator in a durable-goods
[*729] market could not effectively use its patent to earn profits as a reward for
innovation. Hence, a rule against lease-only contracts would eliminate the
patent incentive in markets for durable goods. Antitrust law would thwart
patent law. n120
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n120 This argument differs from another liked better by economists than
lawyers: antitrust law should encourage
all innovation, patentable or unpatentable. The other argument says that if a firm
innovates, but does not patent its innovation, it should still be able to use a
lease-only policy during the period before imitation occurs to allow temporary
monopoly profits as an incentive for innovation. For a similar argument as to
why price discrimination should
always be allowed in an innovative market, see Hausman
& MacKie-Mason,
supra note 95.
Judge Wyzanski, however, considered and rejected this economist's argument:
To this defense the shortest answer is that the law does not allow an
enterprise that maintains control of a market through practices not
economically inevitable, to justify that control because of its supposed social
advantage. . . . It is for Congress, not for private interests, to determine
whether a monopoly, not compelled by circumstances, is advantageous.
110 F. Supp. at 345 (citation omitted). Judge Wyzanski seemed to mean to include judges in his
reference to
"private interests."
Cf.
Bonito Boats, Inc. v. Thunder Craft Boats, Inc., 109 S. Ct. 971 (1989) (preempting effort by state government to offer protection for an unpatentable
innovation);
Fashion Originators' Guild of Am. v. FTC, 312 U.S. 457 (1941) (outlawing boycott effort to protect unpatented fashion creations).
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
C. Shoe: A Wagging Dog
The Coase Conjecture supports the
Shoe rule, but only in a greatly altered form. The case raises a genuine antitrust
problem: a monopolist that injures the public by insisting on a policy of
renting. Coase's logic shows that the only effective way to combat the problem
is to forbid leasing altogether, not simply to order the monopolist to offer a
sales option. This rule is simple, but it can give firms the unfortunate
incentive to make flimsy products so that their sales more nearly resemble the
forbidden leases. More importantly, antitrust errs if it responds by banning
all monopoly leases because this form of transaction often offers great
benefits without any threat at all.
We have outlined the ways in which antitrust
law should tailor any ban on lease-only policies. Having done so, we doubt that
a court should adopt that ban. Our analysis shows that a sensible prohibition
must make dichotomies of three continua. First, the rule should permit
monopolists to lease
"somewhat but not very durable" goods, but not durable goods. Second, the rule should permit them to lease
when technological change is rapid, but not when it is slow. Third, the rule
should permit them to lease for long terms, but not for short. Moreover, the
analysis shows that courts should recognize further exceptions in the presence
of
"effective"
[*730] price discrimination and when monopoly is due to (and not just accompanied by)
patents.
Theorists are comfortable with vague terms like
"durable,"
"rapid,"
"long,"
"effective," and
"due to." But courts must assess particular facts and conclude either
"liable" or
"not liable." More importantly, judges
must invent future economic policy by deciding past antitrust disputes. They
rightfully worry that the rules they craft might channel corporate conduct in
ways that, on balance, will hurt consumers. The inevitable arbitrariness of a
particular solution is not, of course, a reason automatically to reject it.
n121 But arbitrariness does not just look bad. It also risks deterring valuable
conduct. Given the frequent benefits from leasing, rational decision making
advises that we should ignore its potential evils if they are too
inconsequential for note. n122
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n121 Law routinely confronts such problems and pushes on, with bravery or
modesty or resignation. Antitrust doctrine offers its share of such instances.
See
United States v. Aluminum Co. of Am., 148 F.2d 416 (2d Cir. 1945) (the famous
"Rule of Hand" for translating market share statistics into monopoly power conclusions:
30% means no power; 60% is maybe; 90% is certainly monopoly power); Wiley,
Reciprocal Altruism as a Felony: Antitrust and the Prisoner's Dilemma,
86 MICH. L. REV. 1906, 1928 (1988) (merger law and federal Merger Guidelines depend on numerically precise, but
analytically arbitrary, thresholds).
n122 Easterbrook makes an argument of this form about antitrust treatment of
predatory pricing. Easterbrook,
Predatory Strategies and Counterstrategies,
48 U. CHI. L. REV. 263 (1981). Indeed, Judge Wyzanski himself was quite eloquent about the need for judges to
be modest about their ability to transform economic theory into legal rules.
See
110 F. Supp. at 347-48.
Our conclusions here apply only to the support that Coase offered for the full
breadth of the
Shoe rule and not for the far more limited ban on exclusionary
conduct that we discuss
supra in note 37.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -End Footnotes- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
We view the monopolist that leases durable goods in this light. Leasing usually
is desirable. Only quite exceptionally will it facilitate monopoly pricing.
Therefore, only with the loss of much wheat can antitrust cast out the chaff.
Better that the Sherman Act enter the 1990s with more fiber in its diet.
CONCLUSION
* The
Shoe case bans lease-only policies by monopolists. But the court erred in believing
that monopoly pricing could explain United Shoe Machinery's complex of leasing
policies. At best, this explanation only accounts for a few details of the
case. The bulk of the company's conduct seems simply efficient -- thus
suggesting that the
Shoe decision was wrong and its later precedential consequences pernicious.
[*731] As Posner correctly noted, the Coase Conjecture might seem to make some sense
of
Shoe's
ban on monopoly leasing -- under some circumstances. Indeed, the Conjecture
even suggests that the
Shoe rule may have been too narrow. At the same time, however, the Conjecture
dictates that the
Shoe rule be confined in other ways that the opinion did not suggest and that are
unacceptably costly to accomplish. Courts would do well to accept that Coase
describes a problem that is real. But they would also do well to accept it as a
problem not worth solving.